“The substance of the eminent Socialist
gentleman's speech is that making a profit is a sin, but it is my belief that
the real sin is taking a loss.”
Sir Winston Churchill
What if the ‘real sin’ is neither, but to
engage in a particular economic activity in the first place? Is it a sin
to leave the rainforest alone, or is it ecocide to destroy it?
Conventional economics is not neutral
about the desirability of economic activity. It places no limit to the
extent of the economy. Nor does conventional politics. The
centuries-old battle of ideas between laissez-faire and State intervention is
over which can achieve the most growth in the shortest time at the lowest cost.
Is growth necessary? If growth is
zero, the same quantity of goods and services is constantly being brought into
being, so provided the workforce to produce them and the population to consume
them also remain constant, no-one is any worse off than before. The lack
of growth causes panic only because so many decisions are based on the idea
that growth will continue, and so it must continue. In this game, the only
options for those in control of the economic process are to increase their
income through attacking the environment (growth) or through attacking society
(austerity). Just stopping the treadmill is unthinkable.
In reality, the model has to be modified
in a number of ways. Population is not constant: even within a constant
total there will be ongoing changes in the age structure that affect the size
of the working population. Natural resource costs are not constant
either: as the energy cost of accessing resources increases, so does the
overall cost even of maintaining a constant output of goods and services.
The implications are that we ought to be debating what kind of society we wish
to see in the future, and within what limits, rather than blindly following the
assumption that we can have more of everything yet lose nothing important in
the process.
Public policy, which is well-placed to
uphold the holistic view that the economy is a wholly-owned subsidiary of the
environment and not the other way round, is increasingly not up to the job of
framing that rounded debate. The problem of regulatory capture
is becoming acute, with even the most environmental of national agencies, such
as English Heritage and Natural England, now seeing their remits redefined to
support development at pretty much any cost. Massive damage is happening,
but we are assured either that we are wrong to perceive it as negative at all
or that the benefits outweigh the harm. Either way, it is our values and
priorities that are attacked as the ‘problem’, not the damage that is being
done to them.
There is no clear mandate from the
electorate for governments to implement a totalitarian liberal agenda – one
that marginalises any view that there is more to life than consumption – yet
that agenda is being rolled out anyway. The idea that the State should
promote pro-growth policies is an old one, but one previously balanced by
others. One traditional conception of the State is as neutral adjudicator
between competing interests. It is a role that cannot be fulfilled if the
State has repeatedly thrown in its lot with one side.
Libertarians may point out the extent to
which fiscal considerations compel the State to back the ‘wealth creators’, to
the detriment of others, in order to go on funding its spending
commitments. It is certainly worth asking if the UK is living beyond its means precisely because
it is the UK.
Radical decentralisation – and even independence in some areas – could cut the
cost of government substantially by reducing distances between the
decision-makers and their decisions, as well as by curbing unproductive
military expenditure. (Libertarians in fact tend to be quite protective
of the coercive forces of the State: they’ll happily pay for the security of
others’ persons and property, just not their education or healthcare.)
But radical decentralisation also risks empowering those with a democratic,
anti-growth agenda, potentially placing barriers in the path of universal growth, and so
has many enemies.
Research suggests that large industries
are very good at capturing large governments and then using them in ways that
are detrimental to local areas that lack the constitutional power to
resist. The much more robust response to the financial crisis in Iceland as compared with that in the UK – or the EU
generally – illustrates the point. The reverse may also be true – that
small governments are vulnerable to capture by small industries concentrated in
small areas. The domination of local councils in seaside resorts by
hoteliers and restaurateurs is a familiar theme in Wessex. There seems much less
reason, however, to suggest that this isn’t what local voters want. A
balance seems most likely to be achieved where there is a diversity of
industries, in terms of both range and scale, such as might be expected at the
regional level or in areas not dominated by one sector that is a major source
of public revenue.
Other means of limiting regulatory capture
include appointing staff with a public or voluntary sector background in
preference to those with a business background. The whole ‘revolving
door’ culture which has been assiduously cultivated over the past 35 years has
been fatal to perceptions of integrity but is the inevitable consequence of
disregarding the need for government to remain neutral when dealing with
commercial interests. ‘Experience of the real world’ isn’t helpful if all
that is learnt is the fine art of corruption. How are politicians to rely
on impartial advice that is potentially tainted, by past connections or future
prospects? The rebuilding of integrity in public administration is as
important as devolution itself in creating the kind of Wessex we wish
to see. Why not have more of a ‘them’ and ‘us’ relationship between
business and government? It’s a whole lot healthier, because it isn’t the
job of government to help the private sector. It’s the job of government
to govern.
One other side-effect of the revolving
door culture has been the corruption of the language, so that the democratic
sector now sees itself as serving ‘customers’ (rather than
patients, students, arrestees and so on). The implication is that all
relationships can be, and ought to be, reduced to cash, which in turn reinforces
the idea that life is economics and economics alone. The democratic
sector needs to be different in its whole outlook from the commercial sector,
precisely because its difference is its justification. Making things
‘more businesslike’ can be a catchy way of saying that there should be a
constant search for efficiency but take the analogy too far and the
organisation ends up totally efficient but totally ineffective.
Last month, the Leader of Blaby District
Council, in Mercia,
took the astonishing step of describing himself as naïve in believing his party’s policy on localism, as it
had been expressed in opposition. Yet he’s still a member of that
party. To overthrow the tyranny of growth before it wipes out every
decent human value requires a whole range of actions. Mass resignations
from the London
parties, of course. But also the replacement of political structures that
privilege the least attractive economic interests with new structures that
place decision-making beyond their grasp. That revolution starts in the
mind, with a simple substitution of loyalty to Wessex
for a worn-out loyalty to London
that has been comprehensively betrayed.
Wednesday, January 1, 2014
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
1 comment:
http://ukgeneralelection2015.blogspot.co.uk/2014/01/1st-anniversary-poll.html
Hi we are holding a 1st anniversary poll, and the Wessex Regionalists are included. Feel free to vote
Post a Comment